Hi, (sorry me again; encourage other SP9 students to also post their Qs as this isn't my private forum!)
Appreciate any answers to six Questions below on Chapter 14 Intro to Risk Measurement.
Page 5 of the Acted notes defines subadditivity as "A merger of risk situations does not increase the overall level of risk. Indeed, it may decrease the overall level of risk, as a consequence of diversification"
Page 6 explains the 'Positive homogeneity principle' with "if you consider two identical organisations that carry out exactly the same transactions, you would indeed expect the total capital required to protect both of them to be just double the amount required for each"
Q1: Surely a merger of risk could also concentrate risk and so a firm with 100% (£1mn) of assets invested in Bond A should hold more capital than the sum of 2 firms invested 50% (£.5mn) each in Bond A? So please explain the rationale for the subadditivity and Positive homogeneity principles.
Page 5 continues: "subadditivity makes decentralisation of risk-management systems possible, since constraints can be placed on business units and if they stay within these constraints then the overall risk level cannot exceed the sum of the parts."
Q2: How is this derived from the 'sub-additivity' principle?
Q3: For the purpose of SP9, do I need to understand why the Value-at-risk (VaR) measure is only sub-additive for elliptical distributions (page 37) while tail Var is always sub-additive? Or enough to just know this fact. [Guess it's because VaR & any percentile-measure requires ordering losses by size and this order will change with the addition of a new risk, resulting in an adjusted percentile value]
Section 1.2 of the Acted notes (page 6) gives a one-line formula for 'convexity' and adds the fact: "Convexity follows from the axioms of subadditivity and positive homogeneity." The solution to Q14.10 (iii) (bottom of page 37) defines convexity "that by diversifying across different projects the amount of risk is reduced and the corresponding amount of risk capital is reduced."
Q4: This description (page 37) of convexity appears identical to the axiom of subadditivity rather than positive homogeneity. Please provide a clearer explanation in words of what a convex risk measure actually is. Or is it an unintuitive measure that simply ticks the subadditivity and positive homogeneity boxes?
Page 16 of the Acted notes mentions a disadvantage of the empirical approach to calculate VaR: "the practical difficulties and limitations of [linear] interpolation"
Q5: What are these difficulties and limitations and surprised they still exist even with modern computing capabilities?
Page 17 of the Acted notes discussing the derivation of a stochastic VaR includes: "bootstrapped – the losses used to calculate the VaR are derived from random sampling of past observed returns."
Q6: For the purpose of SP9, do I need to understand how bootstrapping works? If yes, appreciate if someone can provide a quick explanation of a bootstrapping process or helpful source to see a relevant example .
Many thanks
Appreciate any answers to six Questions below on Chapter 14 Intro to Risk Measurement.
Page 5 of the Acted notes defines subadditivity as "A merger of risk situations does not increase the overall level of risk. Indeed, it may decrease the overall level of risk, as a consequence of diversification"
Page 6 explains the 'Positive homogeneity principle' with "if you consider two identical organisations that carry out exactly the same transactions, you would indeed expect the total capital required to protect both of them to be just double the amount required for each"
Q1: Surely a merger of risk could also concentrate risk and so a firm with 100% (£1mn) of assets invested in Bond A should hold more capital than the sum of 2 firms invested 50% (£.5mn) each in Bond A? So please explain the rationale for the subadditivity and Positive homogeneity principles.
Page 5 continues: "subadditivity makes decentralisation of risk-management systems possible, since constraints can be placed on business units and if they stay within these constraints then the overall risk level cannot exceed the sum of the parts."
Q2: How is this derived from the 'sub-additivity' principle?
Q3: For the purpose of SP9, do I need to understand why the Value-at-risk (VaR) measure is only sub-additive for elliptical distributions (page 37) while tail Var is always sub-additive? Or enough to just know this fact. [Guess it's because VaR & any percentile-measure requires ordering losses by size and this order will change with the addition of a new risk, resulting in an adjusted percentile value]
Section 1.2 of the Acted notes (page 6) gives a one-line formula for 'convexity' and adds the fact: "Convexity follows from the axioms of subadditivity and positive homogeneity." The solution to Q14.10 (iii) (bottom of page 37) defines convexity "that by diversifying across different projects the amount of risk is reduced and the corresponding amount of risk capital is reduced."
Q4: This description (page 37) of convexity appears identical to the axiom of subadditivity rather than positive homogeneity. Please provide a clearer explanation in words of what a convex risk measure actually is. Or is it an unintuitive measure that simply ticks the subadditivity and positive homogeneity boxes?
Page 16 of the Acted notes mentions a disadvantage of the empirical approach to calculate VaR: "the practical difficulties and limitations of [linear] interpolation"
Q5: What are these difficulties and limitations and surprised they still exist even with modern computing capabilities?
Page 17 of the Acted notes discussing the derivation of a stochastic VaR includes: "bootstrapped – the losses used to calculate the VaR are derived from random sampling of past observed returns."
Q6: For the purpose of SP9, do I need to understand how bootstrapping works? If yes, appreciate if someone can provide a quick explanation of a bootstrapping process or helpful source to see a relevant example .
Many thanks